To be clear I have zero stroke with them but it got hit with a thumbs up, so hopefully they got around to it.
Hopefully! Maybe they’ll want to make an HOI4 mos out of it 🤪
I thought Kim was the king himself lol, thanks for clarification
Nah, that’s Gojong. The Andong Kim clan were the Royal family (sort of), but the King’s name is Gojong.

(Caveat that you can throw a rock in Korea and there’s good odds it lands on somebody named Kim, so it’s easy to lose track!)
 
Sindicat-Generale Belgique
That would be ' Syndicat Général de Belgique' (for General Syndicate of Belgium , more territorial name).

The irony that General Syndicates identified themselves by their country of origin was certainly lost on them).
They'll probably argue this is a territorial distinction rather than a national one (that would be called Belgian General Syndicate otherwise, not 'of Belgium').
 
The Root of the Problem: The Tumultuous Term of America's 29th President
"...core conceits of Blainism, proven wrong multiple times previously but especially so in the Root era, was that the Liberals would eschew personalist patronage and instead hire "wise and sober statesmen," invariably university educated and often from wealthy families, as a form of noblesse oblige of the American variety to find smart and capable bureaucrats with which to staff the administration. One can already see in the choices of Presidents Hay and Foraker that this wasn't true, and despite his reputation for managing the war, Hughes churned through two mediocre War Secretaries, by far the most important position in the Cabinet, before finding a competent man in Stimson. By the time the 1916 elections rolled around, it wasn't even apparent that the electorate believed it anymore - but Elihu Root, possibly the most ardent disciple of the school of James G. Blaine, most certainly did, and it destroyed his Presidency.

For a man who was not President, Andrew Mellon has nonetheless retained an outsized position in the annals of American history, looming above the period of 1917-21 like a dark shadow, a specter behind every corner and decision taken during those years. His influence was not just pernicious, but avoidable; unlike Lodge or Stimson, Mellon was not friends with Root and had been placed in his Cabinet at the behest of Penrose and Knox, which to many observers - chief amongst them Hughes, whose advice to sack Mellon was ignored several times - suggested that Root either tacitly agreed with Mellon's economic program in its entirety, or that he was lazy and craven when it came to enforcing Presidential power in the Cabinet. As tensions advanced between the various protagonists of the Root administration, culminating with Stimson's resignation in February 1918 when he saw it was clear that Mellon was the ascendant figure, the President seemed almost incapable, if not unwilling, to manage their strident personalities, leaving the impression of a government that was not just a failure on policy grounds, but so inept as to be unable to even govern itself.

Mellon was, surprisingly enough, not a controversial figure upon entering Cabinet. He was a wealthy and respected Pittsburgh banker, his family's bank a major factor in financing concerns such as Carnegie (later US) Steel, [1] Alcoa, Westinghouse, Gulf Oil, and a generous benefactor to the new College of Industrial Science at the prestigious University of Pittsburgh - a college know known as Mellon College. [2] Mellon had even been a critical figure in the war effort, leading war bond drives and financing the government's war operations at generous, below-market rates of interest. He had thus ingratiated himself with Liberal movers and shakers both in the Pennsylvania machine and generally in Pennsylvania as he was perceived as being less imperious than the Wall Street bankers such as George Baker; it was also the case that he was, at first, reluctant to enter public life, for outside of banking circles he had been a highly obscure figure.

He was also perhaps one of the Liberal Party's most dogmatically conservative men, and had indeed privately opposed Hughes' potential renomination "for fear of what collectivist programs he may invent in a second term." Even a conservative figure like Root engendered some skepticism in him, what with Root's support for an income tax, and as such Mellon partly saw his role in the Root administration as serving as its "moral spine," particularly in opposition to Stimson. As demobilization plans were drafted in early 1917, for instance, Mellon pushed back at Stimson's proposal for reducing war contracts gradually over the course of six months and selling spare kit to China and Korea at market value, insisting instead that no contracts be renewed at expiry and that more men be demobilized more rapidly due to "the strain upon the Treasury." Mellon's obsession, indeed, was with balancing the national budget and reducing the government's war debts, efforts in which he was successful, but at the cost of the functional economy.

This was not to say that Mellon was entirely inflexible; Cabinet notes from as early as May of 1917 revealed his concession that the conservative dream of entirely repealing the income tax from the Revenue Act of 1910 was not just "immediately impractical, but financially irresponsible and politically suicidal" in the face of major debts, and there were enough progressive Liberal Senators opposed to a massive reduction in the tax. He also was, unsurprisingly for a figure from industrial Pittsburgh, considerably more favorable of tariffs than his average co-partisan, and advocated for a "scientific tax" using new tariffs to not only raise revenue to offset the income tax reduction and pay off war debts, but also protect American industries as they repositioned from wartime to peacetime. This "Mellon Plan," which he first outlined as early as April of 1917, intended to accomplish a number of things - it was meant to balance the budget, increase the disposable income of average Americans while protecting the viability of their industrial work, and encourage the wealthy to transfer their investments from tax-free municipal bonds to higher-yielding and taxable corporate bonds by improving industrial revenues. [3]

On paper, and according to the economic orthodoxies of the time, it was a perfectly fine, though uncreative, plan. But an economy is not on paper, and includes real people and real inputs, and from the viewpoint of modern day, the issues with it look apparent. Millions of people, primarily men, had immigrated to the United States during the 1910s, with a small increase in those figures in tandem with the Great American War itself as factories needed more bodies; as the war economy came to a sudden halt - thanks to Mellon's insistence on not staggering out contracts - factories had to close to retool, laying off hundreds of thousands in the space of weeks across the country, and by late summer, unemployment was perhaps so high that one in ten men, and over one in five working women, were without a job. The return of tens of thousands of foreigners, especially Italians, after the war years alleviated this a little, but the mounting employment crisis would only advance deep into 1918, generally regarded as the peak of the postwar depression, when as many as one in five men were without work for well over a year, many if not most of them veterans. Minneapolis thus looked to be the beginning rather than the end; mining strikes erupted in Wyoming's coalfields in November 1917, socialist railroad workers walked off the job in northern Idaho weeks later, and shipyard and longshoremen strikes rippled across the West Coast in waves from Seattle to Oakland to San Pedro deep into early 1918.

Part of Mellon's assumption in not getting instantly involved in the demand-side equation of the American economy as unemployment ballooned and class tensions spiked - most clearly evidenced in the Minneapolis general strike of June 1917 - was that factories would quickly pivot back to peacetime and that pent-up demand for "normalcy" would lead to a boom of consumer spending as relieved war veterans returned. To say that this assumption was wrong would be an understatement. War rationing had been coordinated between the Department of War and local Supply Boards, and thus was not necessarily an entirely federal endeavor. States were, individually, caught between a rock and a hard place; rationing had been seen as a point of pride and sacrifice on the home front during the war, but many veterans who returned home and their families harbored similar assumptions as their reactionary Treasury Secretary, that the world would start to return to normal once they came back. Some Supply Boards had slowly eased up on rationing as early as the March to the Sea with phased, scientific suspensions; these were typically the most successful ones, with the Denver Supply Board being viewed as having stuck the landing perhaps the best anywhere in the country. Most counties and localities, however, either simply ended rationing all at once, particularly in March and April of 1917 after Root's inauguration and the euphoria that came with the Treaty of Mount Vernon being signed, or in the opposite direction maintained their strict rationing deep into late 1917.

There was no good answer, because both warped the consumer economy that Mellon and Root were banking on to carry the Republic back to some sense of normalcy, and the spectacular unemployment crisis was thus immediately paired with a remarkable inflation crisis as well, not unlike the one gripping Brazil and Argentina but this one at the heart of the world's largest industrial economy. The swell of unemployed persons, which was coupled with a commensurate slump or freeze in wages, occurred at a time when scarce goods were available for the first time unrationed in years and thus demand spiked through the roof. Automobiles, which had been gradually rising in popularity immediately before the war despite a severe crisis in the automotive sector in 1911 that saw dozens of manufacturers shutter, were as much as eleven times as expensive as they had been in 1913, when they certainly were not cheap; certain foodstuffs cost three or four times more, and clothes were often twice as expensive, all at a time when people had less money, if they had any, than in recent memory. A particularly acute crisis emerged in housing; many workers had been housed in temporary wartime barracks at factories that were torn down shortly after the war ended, and about a third as many new homes had been constructed per annum during the period 1913-16 as had been built between 1910-12. With the swell of foreign workers and now returning veterans, which brought with it the start of the postwar "baby boom," the lack of housing was an acute crisis that forced thousands in already-cramped tenement dwellings into even worse squalor, while thousands more began living in shantytowns on the peripheries of cities, often in or near abandoned industrial lots, that quickly earned the monikers "Mellonvilles" or "Rootburgs" in mockery of the distant men in Philadelphia they pointedly blamed for their troubles.

By the autumn of 1917 it was clear that there would be no "return to normalcy," and that between the industrial strikes, ethnic riots against Negroes and European immigrants in many cities, and spiraling cycle of poverty that was exacerbated by bank failures as industrial production declined sharply, the Root administration had a bonafide crisis on its hands. But economic orthodoxy of the time dictated that the government not intervene; even in the Hearst era, coming out of the Panic of 1904, that historically progressive administration had not considered counter-cyclical stimulus of the kind that would eventually become economic consensus, rather instead proposing new bureaus and agencies to regulate economic activity to prevent such a crisis again, which they partially succeeded at in seeing to it that the events of 1910-11 were a mere recession, rather than another economic depression. Proposals to deepen the United States' debt load and deploy stimulatory spending were, even then, still relatively fringe, and Mellon was hesitant to even spend money to replenish state unemployment benefits or workers' compensation plans, which in late 1918 looked about to bankrupt several states including Michigan and New Jersey. Relief would have to come from "these matters shaking themselves out," as Mellon haughtily said it.

It is important to state that the structural issues of the 1917-19 postwar depression - a calamity which no economic shock, not even the severe early 1980s credit crisis, the late 1980s oil crisis, or the early 2000s global financial contagion have come close to matching within the United States - would have flummoxed any President and ruined their Presidency. But one has to wonder if Hughes would not have listened to his close confidant Stimson and kept the standing army larger for longer, and continued demand-side spending through government contracts, and while historians have debated what a McClellan Presidency could have looked like, a figure like Mellon did not exist within the Democratic Party. It is also important to note that much of what sank Root was a matter of publicity - he was the oldest President ever elected, and acted as if his ideas were as old as himself, and Mellon was a figure so publicly callous towards the issues effecting the American worker and veteran that he became almost a caricature of a heartless banker and capitalist, a stance that made the general perception of his conservative policies even worse.

The eruption of the Central European War in the spring of 1919 would help lift American factories out of their doldrums and substantially reduced unemployment while filling government tax coffers again to retire war bonds and other debts; this narrowing of the national debt was also what allowed the more ambitious progressive programs of the 1920s to be deployed under a fiscal regime that was much more conservative than its reputation would suggest. Said circumstances would, briefly, lead some conservative Liberals in the 1970s and 1980s to claim that Mellon was proven correct and that the postwar depression was simply a period of unavoidable "hard medicine" coming out of the war economy; but, as late as the 2008 Presidential election, Liberal candidate Roger Goodell was accused in his reelection campaign of "neo-Mellonism," proving the shadow of Mellon's unpopularity was long and enduring many decades after his death..."

- The Root of the Problem: The Tumultuous Term of America's 29th President

[1] Much smaller trust than OTL thanks to antitrust/not absorbing Tennessee Coal and Iron, though still a major conglomerate
[2] Essentially Pitt stays private, and Carnegie Mellon University is a sub-college of it, making it an even more elite campus.
[3] I didn't find a good way to weave this into the narrative, but Mellon was also anti-Prohibition and thought teetotalers were lame, so he's probably not super gung-ho about enforcing the interstate liquor ban coming down the pike, either.
 
America's Pastime: Baseball and Why We Love it
"...perception of scrappy, working-class players. The 1917 baseball season was the first in which a full slate was played since 1912, and it was the first in which the prohibition on Confederate or Texan players was lifted, a prohibition which only really benefitted Shoeless Joe, who had refused to raise arms against the United States and had "twiddled his thumbs" through 1916, bitter and resentful that he was denied a chance to play ball.

The 1917 White Sox came out with a vengeance and returned the center of baseball gravity to Chicago, this time to the South Side, with Jackson returning from hiatus in dominant form. Many of the men who played for the White Sox were veterans of the war, whose thousand-yard stares at bat or in the outfield matched those of the beleaguered spectators in the stands. The White Sox dynasty - which would win, behind Jackson's dominant batting, titles in 1917, 1919, and 1920 - became almost synonymous with the depressed economy and grim social tensions of the time, and their place as one of baseball's great clubs owes just as much to their deep connection to the people of the South Side as it does to their excellent play on the field, punctuated by a defeat of hated crosstown National League rival and recent dynasts, the Cubs, 4-1 in the 1920 World Series..."

- America's Pastime: Baseball and Why We Love it
 
I'm definitely enjoying watching the inept flailing about of the Root Presidency and the post-war chaos which is bringing an end to the Liberal Ascendecy.

I'm surprised that Hughes is such a large and vocal critic of Root, considering he worked so hard to get the man the nomination and Presidency. Are we seeing some shades of OTL Taft-Roosevelt here?
 
But one has to wonder if Hughes would not have listened to his close confidant Stimson and kept the standing army larger for longer, and continued demand-side spending through government contracts, and while historians have debated what a McClellan Presidency could have looked like, a figure like Mellon did not exist within the Democratic Party.
Hey, remember when the body politic had a temper tantrum and voted against Hearst in 1912, thus condemning the country to eight long years of Liberal presidents and their completely inept cabinet secretaries? Hope that hissy fit was worth it guys!

There's no doubt things would be bad under anyone else, but there's also no doubt they wouldn't be this bad under anyone else.
 
I'm definitely enjoying watching the inept flailing about of the Root Presidency and the post-war chaos which is bringing an end to the Liberal Ascendecy.

I'm surprised that Hughes is such a large and vocal critic of Root, considering he worked so hard to get the man the nomination and Presidency. Are we seeing some shades of OTL Taft-Roosevelt here?
Maybe a bit of some shades of that, sure. Though in my head it was more of a "come on, even I fired Herrick eventually, why are you keeping this asshole around?" mentality than anything else, and maybe a bit of ego on Hughes' part thinking he would never make such mistakes such as deferring economics to Mellon.
Hey, remember when the body politic had a temper tantrum and voted against Hearst in 1912, thus condemning the country to eight long years of Liberal presidents and their completely inept cabinet secretaries? Hope that hissy fit was worth it guys!

There's no doubt things would be bad under anyone else, but there's also no doubt they wouldn't be this bad under anyone else.
Well said!
 
"...core conceits of Blainism, proven wrong multiple times previously but especially so in the Root era, was that the Liberals would eschew personalist patronage and instead hire "wise and sober statesmen," invariably university educated and often from wealthy families, as a form of noblesse oblige of the American variety to find smart and capable bureaucrats with which to staff the administration. One can already see in the choices of Presidents Hay and Foraker that this wasn't true, and despite his reputation for managing the war, Hughes churned through two mediocre War Secretaries, by far the most important position in the Cabinet, before finding a competent man in Stimson. By the time the 1916 elections rolled around, it wasn't even apparent that the electorate believed it anymore - but Elihu Root, possibly the most ardent disciple of the school of James G. Blaine, most certainly did, and it destroyed his Presidency.

For a man who was not President, Andrew Mellon has nonetheless retained an outsized position in the annals of American history, looming above the period of 1917-21 like a dark shadow, a specter behind every corner and decision taken during those years. His influence was not just pernicious, but avoidable; unlike Lodge or Stimson, Mellon was not friends with Root and had been placed in his Cabinet at the behest of Penrose and Knox, which to many observers - chief amongst them Hughes, whose advice to sack Mellon was ignored several times - suggested that Root either tacitly agreed with Mellon's economic program in its entirety, or that he was lazy and craven when it came to enforcing Presidential power in the Cabinet. As tensions advanced between the various protagonists of the Root administration, culminating with Stimson's resignation in February 1918 when he saw it was clear that Mellon was the ascendant figure, the President seemed almost incapable, if not unwilling, to manage their strident personalities, leaving the impression of a government that was not just a failure on policy grounds, but so inept as to be unable to even govern itself.

Mellon was, surprisingly enough, not a controversial figure upon entering Cabinet. He was a wealthy and respected Pittsburgh banker, his family's bank a major factor in financing concerns such as Carnegie (later US) Steel, [1] Alcoa, Westinghouse, Gulf Oil, and a generous benefactor to the new College of Industrial Science at the prestigious University of Pittsburgh - a college know known as Mellon College. [2] Mellon had even been a critical figure in the war effort, leading war bond drives and financing the government's war operations at generous, below-market rates of interest. He had thus ingratiated himself with Liberal movers and shakers both in the Pennsylvania machine and generally in Pennsylvania as he was perceived as being less imperious than the Wall Street bankers such as George Baker; it was also the case that he was, at first, reluctant to enter public life, for outside of banking circles he had been a highly obscure figure.

He was also perhaps one of the Liberal Party's most dogmatically conservative men, and had indeed privately opposed Hughes' potential renomination "for fear of what collectivist programs he may invent in a second term." Even a conservative figure like Root engendered some skepticism in him, what with Root's support for an income tax, and as such Mellon partly saw his role in the Root administration as serving as its "moral spine," particularly in opposition to Stimson. As demobilization plans were drafted in early 1917, for instance, Mellon pushed back at Stimson's proposal for reducing war contracts gradually over the course of six months and selling spare kit to China and Korea at market value, insisting instead that no contracts be renewed at expiry and that more men be demobilized more rapidly due to "the strain upon the Treasury." Mellon's obsession, indeed, was with balancing the national budget and reducing the government's war debts, efforts in which he was successful, but at the cost of the functional economy.

This was not to say that Mellon was entirely inflexible; Cabinet notes from as early as May of 1917 revealed his concession that the conservative dream of entirely repealing the income tax from the Revenue Act of 1910 was not just "immediately impractical, but financially irresponsible and politically suicidal" in the face of major debts, and there were enough progressive Liberal Senators opposed to a massive reduction in the tax. He also was, unsurprisingly for a figure from industrial Pittsburgh, considerably more favorable of tariffs than his average co-partisan, and advocated for a "scientific tax" using new tariffs to not only raise revenue to offset the income tax reduction and pay off war debts, but also protect American industries as they repositioned from wartime to peacetime. This "Mellon Plan," which he first outlined as early as April of 1917, intended to accomplish a number of things - it was meant to balance the budget, increase the disposable income of average Americans while protecting the viability of their industrial work, and encourage the wealthy to transfer their investments from tax-free municipal bonds to higher-yielding and taxable corporate bonds by improving industrial revenues. [3]

On paper, and according to the economic orthodoxies of the time, it was a perfectly fine, though uncreative, plan. But an economy is not on paper, and includes real people and real inputs, and from the viewpoint of modern day, the issues with it look apparent. Millions of people, primarily men, had immigrated to the United States during the 1910s, with a small increase in those figures in tandem with the Great American War itself as factories needed more bodies; as the war economy came to a sudden halt - thanks to Mellon's insistence on not staggering out contracts - factories had to close to retool, laying off hundreds of thousands in the space of weeks across the country, and by late summer, unemployment was perhaps so high that one in ten men, and over one in five working women, were without a job. The return of tens of thousands of foreigners, especially Italians, after the war years alleviated this a little, but the mounting employment crisis would only advance deep into 1918, generally regarded as the peak of the postwar depression, when as many as one in five men were without work for well over a year, many if not most of them veterans. Minneapolis thus looked to be the beginning rather than the end; mining strikes erupted in Wyoming's coalfields in November 1917, socialist railroad workers walked off the job in northern Idaho weeks later, and shipyard and longshoremen strikes rippled across the West Coast in waves from Seattle to Oakland to San Pedro deep into early 1918.

Part of Mellon's assumption in not getting instantly involved in the demand-side equation of the American economy as unemployment ballooned and class tensions spiked - most clearly evidenced in the Minneapolis general strike of June 1917 - was that factories would quickly pivot back to peacetime and that pent-up demand for "normalcy" would lead to a boom of consumer spending as relieved war veterans returned. To say that this assumption was wrong would be an understatement. War rationing had been coordinated between the Department of War and local Supply Boards, and thus was not necessarily an entirely federal endeavor. States were, individually, caught between a rock and a hard place; rationing had been seen as a point of pride and sacrifice on the home front during the war, but many veterans who returned home and their families harbored similar assumptions as their reactionary Treasury Secretary, that the world would start to return to normal once they came back. Some Supply Boards had slowly eased up on rationing as early as the March to the Sea with phased, scientific suspensions; these were typically the most successful ones, with the Denver Supply Board being viewed as having stuck the landing perhaps the best anywhere in the country. Most counties and localities, however, either simply ended rationing all at once, particularly in March and April of 1917 after Root's inauguration and the euphoria that came with the Treaty of Mount Vernon being signed, or in the opposite direction maintained their strict rationing deep into late 1917.

There was no good answer, because both warped the consumer economy that Mellon and Root were banking on to carry the Republic back to some sense of normalcy, and the spectacular unemployment crisis was thus immediately paired with a remarkable inflation crisis as well, not unlike the one gripping Brazil and Argentina but this one at the heart of the world's largest industrial economy. The swell of unemployed persons, which was coupled with a commensurate slump or freeze in wages, occurred at a time when scarce goods were available for the first time unrationed in years and thus demand spiked through the roof. Automobiles, which had been gradually rising in popularity immediately before the war despite a severe crisis in the automotive sector in 1911 that saw dozens of manufacturers shutter, were as much as eleven times as expensive as they had been in 1913, when they certainly were not cheap; certain foodstuffs cost three or four times more, and clothes were often twice as expensive, all at a time when people had less money, if they had any, than in recent memory. A particularly acute crisis emerged in housing; many workers had been housed in temporary wartime barracks at factories that were torn down shortly after the war ended, and about a third as many new homes had been constructed per annum during the period 1913-16 as had been built between 1910-12. With the swell of foreign workers and now returning veterans, which brought with it the start of the postwar "baby boom," the lack of housing was an acute crisis that forced thousands in already-cramped tenement dwellings into even worse squalor, while thousands more began living in shantytowns on the peripheries of cities, often in or near abandoned industrial lots, that quickly earned the monikers "Mellonvilles" or "Rootburgs" in mockery of the distant men in Philadelphia they pointedly blamed for their troubles.

By the autumn of 1917 it was clear that there would be no "return to normalcy," and that between the industrial strikes, ethnic riots against Negroes and European immigrants in many cities, and spiraling cycle of poverty that was exacerbated by bank failures as industrial production declined sharply, the Root administration had a bonafide crisis on its hands. But economic orthodoxy of the time dictated that the government not intervene; even in the Hearst era, coming out of the Panic of 1904, that historically progressive administration had not considered counter-cyclical stimulus of the kind that would eventually become economic consensus, rather instead proposing new bureaus and agencies to regulate economic activity to prevent such a crisis again, which they partially succeeded at in seeing to it that the events of 1910-11 were a mere recession, rather than another economic depression. Proposals to deepen the United States' debt load and deploy stimulatory spending were, even then, still relatively fringe, and Mellon was hesitant to even spend money to replenish state unemployment benefits or workers' compensation plans, which in late 1918 looked about to bankrupt several states including Michigan and New Jersey. Relief would have to come from "these matters shaking themselves out," as Mellon haughtily said it.

It is important to state that the structural issues of the 1917-19 postwar depression - a calamity which no economic shock, not even the severe early 1980s credit crisis, the late 1980s oil crisis, or the early 2000s global financial contagion have come close to matching within the United States - would have flummoxed any President and ruined their Presidency. But one has to wonder if Hughes would not have listened to his close confidant Stimson and kept the standing army larger for longer, and continued demand-side spending through government contracts, and while historians have debated what a McClellan Presidency could have looked like, a figure like Mellon did not exist within the Democratic Party. It is also important to note that much of what sank Root was a matter of publicity - he was the oldest President ever elected, and acted as if his ideas were as old as himself, and Mellon was a figure so publicly callous towards the issues effecting the American worker and veteran that he became almost a caricature of a heartless banker and capitalist, a stance that made the general perception of his conservative policies even worse.

The eruption of the Central European War in the spring of 1919 would help lift American factories out of their doldrums and substantially reduced unemployment while filling government tax coffers again to retire war bonds and other debts; this narrowing of the national debt was also what allowed the more ambitious progressive programs of the 1920s to be deployed under a fiscal regime that was much more conservative than its reputation would suggest. Said circumstances would, briefly, lead some conservative Liberals in the 1970s and 1980s to claim that Mellon was proven correct and that the postwar depression was simply a period of unavoidable "hard medicine" coming out of the war economy; but, as late as the 2008 Presidential election, Liberal candidate Roger Goodell was accused in his reelection campaign of "neo-Mellonism," proving the shadow of Mellon's unpopularity was long and enduring many decades after his death..."

- The Root of the Problem: The Tumultuous Term of America's 29th President

[1] Much smaller trust than OTL thanks to antitrust/not absorbing Tennessee Coal and Iron, though still a major conglomerate
[2] Essentially Pitt stays private, and Carnegie Mellon University is a sub-college of it, making it an even more elite campus.
[3] I didn't find a good way to weave this into the narrative, but Mellon was also anti-Prohibition and thought teetotalers were lame, so he's probably not super gung-ho about enforcing the interstate liquor ban coming down the pike, either.
As a note on the history of Pitt, Mellon Institute, Carnegie Instititute of Technology iOTL

Pitt was founded privately before the POD and only went public in 1966. The Mellon Institute of Industrial Research was founded in 1913 as a *part* of the University of Pittsburgh, became independent in 1937 and merged with CIT (which had been founded in 1900) to form Carnegie Mellon University in 1967.
So basically, what's in the at this point Mellon Institute is part of Pitt just as it was iOTL. There appear to be two differences from OTL, first, Carnegie apparently either doesn't set up a separate school *or* merges it into Pitt while Mellon Insititute is still there and second, Pitt stays private.

I'm a Carnegie-Mellon Alumnus. The graffiti in the Restrooms over the TP dispensers say "Pitt Diploma, take one" was fairly common...
 
Second Wave: The Postwar Progressive Revolution of 1917-31
"...longstanding position of influence, but would before long have to come to compete with two newcomers, all of which inspired a huge burst of public interest and, ideally for intellectual discourse, competition in the marketplace for more elevated publications geared towards debate around policy.

A major part of this was Roosevelt's frustration that he was unable to simply buy The Nation outright; Oswald Garrison Villard considered himself a nonpartisan above reproach and, despite his increasing sympathy for Democratic policies domestically (he remained until his death in 1949 a committed isolationist who even opposed the bipartisan consensus on interventionism in the "near abroad" of Latin America and the Caribbean), dismissed Roosevelt as a partisan hack who would turn The Nation away from a left-wing periodical aimed at elevating national debate into a "pompous rag" similar to his Journal family of papers. Embittered and insulted, Roosevelt decided to take on "that bastard" and in January 1918 founded American Progress, a progressive publication that was emphatically a Democratic outlet but aimed at a different type of discourse from the Nation, instead becoming a platform for Democratic politicians to reach voters through editorials introducing themselves to a national readership, and providing a forum for policy proposals to be worked through. It was American Progress that spoke to a more emergent middle class rather than working class reader base, and provided a considerably more sophisticated point of view than what was common in partisan dailies or morning papers of that time.

The third leg of the explosion of "publication progressivism" was The New Republic, which had been founded in 1914 with a donation from the Whitney family and had come about in large part to reconcile the progressive zeitgeist of the day with the liberal traditions of middle-class readers who were curious about the massive changes ongoing in the United States, but perhaps uncomfortable or unsure what they meant. The New Republic saw a burst of readership in the immediate postwar years, in part thanks to President Charles Evans Hughes describing the postwar United States as "this new republic" in his famous farewell address in Philadelphia in February of that same year. The name fit; there was a general sense with the American people that there was an America of the past, an "old republic," that had been destroyed in the national gauntlet of the Great American War, and that a new country had been forged in those fires. The publishers of the magazine certainly saw it that way, and took the belief that their publication could perhaps help explain this new paradigm to their readers and become an outlet for them to debate it, understand it, and shape it. Inevitably, this meant that the New Republic eventually became the leading publication of the progressive and moderate wing of the Liberal Party; indeed, John J. Pershing shaped his political views in guest editorials in the paper in the late 1920s, and he made his arguments in favor of his legacy Interstate Transport Act that proposed a network of modern railroads, airports and highways tying together the country as a strategic and economic necessity through the pages of the New Republic to a readership initially skeptical of government interventionism before he ever took to the radio or challenged Congress to pass the act.

The late 1910s thus saw the contest of three very different ideological segments of the second progressive wave; in The Nation, a paper that was explicitly left-wing socially and economically but perhaps naively nonpartisan; an explicitly partisan policy paper for innovative Democrats in American Progress; and New Republic, the voice of a faction of the Liberals. All three of them would elevate debate, in part in an effort to stymie each others' readership, and in that debate, all three of them would create the space for public acceptance of progressive reform as the late 1910s depression ended..."

- Second Wave: The Postwar Progressive Revolution of 1917-31
 
As a note on the history of Pitt, Mellon Institute, Carnegie Instititute of Technology iOTL

Pitt was founded privately before the POD and only went public in 1966. The Mellon Institute of Industrial Research was founded in 1913 as a *part* of the University of Pittsburgh, became independent in 1937 and merged with CIT (which had been founded in 1900) to form Carnegie Mellon University in 1967.
So basically, what's in the at this point Mellon Institute is part of Pitt just as it was iOTL. There appear to be two differences from OTL, first, Carnegie apparently either doesn't set up a separate school *or* merges it into Pitt while Mellon Insititute is still there and second, Pitt stays private.

I'm a Carnegie-Mellon Alumnus. The graffiti in the Restrooms over the TP dispensers say "Pitt Diploma, take one" was fairly common...
Love it! Haha. One of my best friends is also a CMU alum, went to their acting school… and is now a crypto programmer lol.

My thinking with Pitt ITTL and keeping it a private school with CMU still inside is to have it be sort of the Northwestern or Vandy of Pittsburgh - big, prestigious, private research university, probably with a speciality in the sciences
 
Love it! Haha. One of my best friends is also a CMU alum, went to their acting school… and is now a crypto programmer lol.

My thinking with Pitt ITTL and keeping it a private school with CMU still inside is to have it be sort of the Northwestern or Vandy of Pittsburgh - big, prestigious, private research university, probably with a speciality in the sciences
AMAZING work as always!
 
Love it! Haha. One of my best friends is also a CMU alum, went to their acting school… and is now a crypto programmer lol.

My thinking with Pitt ITTL and keeping it a private school with CMU still inside is to have it be sort of the Northwestern or Vandy of Pittsburgh - big, prestigious, private research university, probably with a speciality in the sciences
As someone living in the Pittsburgh area Im down for that lol
 
indeed, John J. Pershing shaped his political views in guest editorials in the paper in the late 1920s, and he made his arguments in favor of his legacy Interstate Transport Act that proposed a network of modern railroads, airports and highways tying together the country as a strategic and economic necessity through the pages of the New Republic to a readership initially skeptical of government interventionism before he ever took to the radio or challenged Congress to pass the act.
Pershing is going to be an industrial president.
Highways and infrastructure
Is he going to be working with Eisenhower...
 
Love it! Haha. One of my best friends is also a CMU alum, went to their acting school… and is now a crypto programmer lol.

My thinking with Pitt ITTL and keeping it a private school with CMU still inside is to have it be sort of the Northwestern or Vandy of Pittsburgh - big, prestigious, private research university, probably with a speciality in the sciences
Even as an alumnus, I'm confused as to how the Acting Department became so well recognized nationally. Engineering, well that's what Carnegie started with. The sciences were buffed by the Mellon Institute. The Robotics effort is really aligned with Carnegie wanted the school.
Duquesne would be an excellent counterpoint there. Would be interesting to see if Case-Western Reserve is its big rival...
 
the 1917-19 postwar depression - a calamity which no economic shock, not even the severe early 1980s credit crisis, the late 1980s oil crisis, or the early 2000s global financial contagion have come close to matching within the United States
So no Great Depression? The Late 1910's is the worst economic shock the U.S. gets? Do the 1930's only see a weak recession, or none at all? (Thus possibly making the Pershing years the Roaring Thirties).
John J. Pershing shaped his political views in guest editorials in the paper in the late 1920s, and he made his arguments in favor of his legacy Interstate Transport Act that proposed a network of modern railroads, airports and highways tying together the country as a strategic and economic necessity
So Pershing as a bit of an Eisenhower analogue?
 
Top